Contrary to the claims of Marxism, economics does not determine the political structure of a country; rather, the political structure of a country determines its economic system. The Soviet Union was proof of that. In the case of the U.S. government, this can be seen in the adoption of tariffs, beginning in 1789. The tariffs served political objectives, not economic needs. More often than not, they worked against the economic interests of the country as a whole. Tariffs were adopted because Washington, Hamilton, and others believed the country’s long-term security required the United States to be economically, as well as politically, independent from the British. The goal of the tariff of 1789, and succeeding tariffs, was to build up local industries to supply local needs and reduce American dependence on British manufacturers. But as with all tariffs, somebody won, and somebody lost.
By 1861, the North was producing goods inferior to British wares and selling them to a captive American market at higher prices. The tariffs collected on British-made goods were being used to fund “internal improvements,” a practice known as the American System. The federal government simply gave public funds to private companies to build the country’s infrastructure: roads, railroads, turnpikes, harbors, and canals. These internal improvements frequently turned out to be more expensive than originally estimated and, if ever completed, were, like the Erie Canal, found to be redundant. The system flourished because the politicians who voted for such federal subsidies were financially rewarded by the businesses that received those public funds. Opponents of the practice denounced it as institutionalized corruption. This patronage system was a boon for Northern commercial interests.
The tariff was the principal cause of the Civil War. It was the reason the South seceded—and the reason the North waged a war against the South’s secession.
It is because of the American System that the secession of the Southern states posed an existential threat to the Northern states. Without the revenue from Southern exports and the tariffs on Southern imports, a union comprising the Northern states would have constituted what today is termed a failed state. At the outbreak of the Civil War, Gen. Winfield Scott, commanding general of the U.S. Army, opined that, without the South, the North would dissolve into three separate republics: West Coast, Midwest, and East Coast. Initially, it appeared likely the North would, in fact, shatter into four independent countries. Democratic Congressman Daniel Sickles and DeBow’s Review, among others, urged New York City to secede from New York state and become “the Republic of New York,” a city state that would flourish through free trade.
Northern newspapers reflected this fear. In an editorial on November 20, 1860, Cleveland’s Daily National Democrat declared,
The entire amount, in dollars and cents, of produce and of manufactured articles exported to foreign countries from the United States for the year ending June, 1858, was $293,758,279, of which amount the raw cotton exported alone amounted to $131,386,661 . . . taking the estimate of the cotton used [in the] North . . . and adding it to the worth of the cotton sent abroad, and we have over one hundred and fifty-eight million dollars[’] worth of cotton as the amount furnished by the South. Deduct from the exports the silver and gold and the foreign goods exported, and the cotton crop of the South alone exported exceeds the other entire export of the United States, and when to this we add the hemp and Naval stores, sugar, rice, and tobacco, produced alone in the Southern States, we have near two-thirds of the value entire of exports from the South. Let the States of the South separate, and the cotton, the rice, hemp, sugar and tobacco, now consumed in the Northern States must be purchased [from the] South, subject to a Tariff duty, greatly enhancing their cost. The cotton factories of New England now, by getting their raw cotton duty free, are enabled to contend with the English in the markets of their own Provinces, and in other parts of the world. A separation would take from us this advantage, and it would take from the vessels owned by the North the carrying trade of the South, now mostly monopolised by them.
On December 10, 1860, an editorial in the Daily Chicago Times affirmed that,
With her immense staples, [the South] has furnished near three-fourths of the entire exports of the country. Last year she furnished seventy-two per cent. of the whole . . . It is almost impossible to estimate the amount of money realized yearly out of the South by the North. It, beyond all question, amounts to hundreds of millions. By the present arrangement, also, we have a tariff that protects our manufacturers from thirty to fifty percent, and enables us to consume large quantities of Southern cotton, and to compete in our whole home market with the skilled labor of Europe. This operates to compel the South to pay an indirect bounty to our skilled labor, of millions annually. The result would follow any tariff, for revenue or otherwise.
But, the Daily Chicago Times continued,
Let us, for a moment, reverse the picture, and look dissolution in the face: At one single blow our foreign commerce must be reduced to less than one-half what it now is. Our coastwise trade would pass into other hands. One-half of our shipping would lie idle at our wharves. We should lose our trade with the South, with all of its immense profits. Our manufacturers would be in utter ruin. Let the South adopt the free-trade system, or that of a tariff for revenue, and these results would alike follow. If protection be wholly withdrawn from our labor, it could not compete, with all the prejudices against it, with the labor of Europe. We should be driven from the market, and millions of our people would be compelled to go out of employment.
In its editorial of January 15, 1861, the Philadelphia Press opined, “It is the enforcement of the revenue laws, NOT the coercion of the State, that is the question of the hour. If those laws cannot be enforced, the Union is clearly gone.”
On March 12, 1861, the New York Evening Post wrote,
That either the revenue from duties must be collected in the ports of the rebel states, or the ports must be closed to importations from abroad, is generally admitted. If neither of these things be done, our revenue laws are substantially repealed; the sources which supply our treasury will be dried up; we shall have no money to carry on the government; the nation will become bankrupt before the next crop of corn is ripe.
The Boston Transcript wrote on March 18, 1861,
now the mask has been thrown off and it is apparent that the people of the principal seceding states are now for commercial independence. They dream that the centres of traffic can be changed from Northern to Southern ports . . . by a revenue system verging on free trade. . . . The government would be false to its obligations if this state of things were not provided against.
An editorial in the Newark Daily Advertiser on April 2, 1861, declared: “We apprehend, that the Cotton States, especially the chief instigator of the present troubles—South Carolina,—have all along for years been preparing the way for the adoption of the policy of free trade.”
The Pittsburgh Post wrote in its editorial on April 2, 1861,
The argument is that by repealing the tariff, the commerce of the North may be enabled to compete with the commerce of the South upon equal footing. Repeal the tariff and place the commercial interest of the nations upon the same footing, and still the North would be the loser and not the gainer thereby.
The tariff was also explicitly cited as the reason for secession in the South. In November 1860, the Charleston Mercury declared,
The real causes of dissatisfaction in the South with the North, are in the unjust taxation and expenditure of the taxes by the Government of the United States, and in the revolution the North has effected in this government from a confederated republic, to a national sectional despotism.
The New Orleans Daily Crescent wrote on January 21, 1861, that the people of the South
know that it is their import trade that draws from the people’s pockets sixty or seventy millions of dollars per annum, in the shape of duties, to be expended mainly in the North, and in the protection and encouragement of Northern interests. . . . These are the reasons why these people do not wish the South to secede from the Union.
British newspapers similarly emphasized the tariff as a cause of the South’s secession. Fraser’s Magazine, in an article entitled “The American Quarrel” (April 1861), observed that
Congress was rapidly passing a new tariff of the most strongest protectionism to Northern manufacturers! . . . The unseemliness of the measure has filled all England with astonishment. It is a new affront and wrong to the slave states, and raises a wall against the return of the seceders.
The December 21, 1861, issue of the Athenaeum commented,
As a rule, the great mass of the public expenditures were made from the North, not in the South, so that Southerners found themselves doubly taxed—taxed first for the benefit of the Northerner manufacturers, and then, in the disbursement of the public funds, denied an equal participation in the benefits accruing therefrom.
As the North’s fear of the loss of its tariff subsidies grew, demands soon appeared for an invasion of the South. In its editorial of May 17, 1861, the Montpelier Daily Green Mountain Freeman advocated such action:
Millions and tens of millions of dollars, due from Southern traders for goods of recent purchase, and now perhaps mostly on their shelves, or due on the most sacred of honorary obligations, have thus been, within the last three months, unblushingly repudiated, and irrevocably lost to the mercantile classes of our cities. . . . Let the North take her pay for all her wronged citizens in real estate, to be taken with less gentle hands than those of a levying Sheriff, and to be settled by her free people, who will convert that land of treason and barbarism into one of law, order, and civil society. Let those who would carp at this suggestion as too agrarian in the treatment of the South, bear in mind that it would be but a mild form of a just retribution . . .
Here is where Fort Sumter in Charleston Harbor, South Carolina, entered the calculations of the North. At the beginning of 1861, on January 19, three months before the Battle of Fort Sumter, the Chicago Daily Tribune declared,
There is yet a single hope for freedom in this crisis, but that hope does not rest on the North. If the South Carolinians would only make a determined assault upon Fort Sumpter, level its walls to the sea, and slaughter its gallant commander and all his men—then perhaps the North would arise in vindication of the Constitution and laws, and teach the South that this country and government were not made wholly for slaveholders. That is now almost our only hope.
In vindication of the Constitution and laws. To what was the Chicago Daily Tribune referring? On April 15, 1861, within 48 hours of the battle, the New York Times provided the answer:
The first act in the drama which has terminated in the surrender of Fort Sumter, instead of being a defeat, is, when we come to look at its effects, a most brilliant success. It has thrown upon the Confederated States the entire responsibility of commencing the war. It has given us time to arm for offensive operations and to collect and to place before every Southern port a fleet sufficient to enforce the revenue laws . . .
President-elect Abraham Lincoln would have agreed. In his letter of December 29, 1860, to James Watson Webb, editor of the New York Courier and Enquirer, Lincoln had written, “I think we should hold the forts, or retake them, as the case may be, and collect the revenue.”
On April 13, 1861, as the Battle of Fort Sumter was ending, Lincoln replied (citing his own First Inaugural Address) to the concerns of a committee from the Virginia Convention,
As I then, and therein, said, I now repeat: “The power confided to me will be used to hold, occupy, and possess, the property, and places belonging to the Government, and to collect the duties and imposts; but, beyond what is necessary for these objects, there will be no invasion—no using of force against, or among the people anywhere” . . . But if, as now appears to be true, in pursuit of a purpose to drive the United States authority from these places, an unprovoked assault has been made upon Fort-Sumpter [sic], I shall hold myself at liberty to repossess, if I can, like places which had been seized before the Government was devolved upon me.
Fulfilling the wishes of the Chicago Daily Tribune’s editorial, Lincoln wrote to Gustavus Fox on May 1, 1861,
You and I both anticipated that the cause of the country would be advanced by making the attempt to provision Fort-Sumpter [sic], even if it should fail; and it is no small consolation now to feel that our anticipation is justified by the result.
The Northern states did not fight the Civil War to end slavery. They waged war upon the South to preserve a political union, which was enriching them through tariffs, internal improvements, and mercantilism. This goal was declared their official policy in the Crittenden-Johnson Resolutions that the U.S. Congress adopted in July 1861:
Resolved . . . That the present deplorable civil war has been forced upon the country by the disunionists of the Southern States now in revolt against the constitutional Government and in arms around the capital; that in this national emergency Congress, banishing all feelings of mere passion or resentment, will recollect only its duty to the whole country; that this war is not waged on our part in any spirit of oppression, nor for any purpose of conquest or subjugation, nor purpose of overthrowing or interfering with the rights or established institutions of those States, but to defend and maintain the supremacy of the Constitution and to preserve the Union, with all the dignity, equality, and rights of the several States unimpaired; and that as soon as these objects are accomplished the war ought to cease.
In 1862, the British Quarterly Review, in its article “The American Crisis,” put the Crittenden-Johnson Resolutions into plain English:
For the contest on the part of the North is now undisguisedly for empire. The question of Slavery is thrown to the winds. There is hardly any concession in its favor that the South could ask which the North would refuse, provided only that the seceding States would re-enter the Union . . . Away with the pretense on the North to dignify its cause with the name of freedom to the slave!
In fact, to keep the Southern states in the Union, Congress passed the Corwin Amendment—the original 13th Amendment—on March 2, 1861, which, if ratified, would have prohibited the federal government from interfering with or abolishing the “domestic institutions” of the Southern states. The Southern states would have none of it. They wanted their political and economic independence. The issue was the tariff, not slavery.
For the contest on the part of the North is now undisguisedly for empire. How would that new order, an empire for the commercial interests of Northern states, differ from the Union from which the Southern states had seceded? The answer was provided by U.S. Sen. John Sherman, brother of Gen. William T. Sherman and chairman of the Senate Finance Committee. In a speech delivered in support of a bill on monetary centralization, he proposed a new system of government that bore a strong resemblance to 20th-century fascism: “All private interests, all local interests, all banking interests, the interests of individuals, everything, should be subordinate now to the interest of the Government.” That the bill’s cosponsor in the House was U.S. Rep. Elbridge G. Spaulding, a New York banker, confirmed “the interest of the Government” was to enrich Northern businessmen.
As Jeffrey Rogers Hummel documents in Emancipating Slaves, Enslaving Free Men: A History of the American Civil War, Sherman’s new system enriched industrialists and financiers such as Andrew Carnegie, J. Pierpont Morgan, and John D. Rockefeller, as well as a host of what are today’s “leading” American families. But much of this new wealth was acquired through fraud. Repelled by the abuse and impelled to take action, Congress enacted the False Claims Act (the “Lincoln Law”) on March 2, 1863, imposing penalties on companies defrauding government programs and encouraging whistle-blowers to come forward by offering them 15 to 25 percent of all recovered damages.
It was too little, too late. By then, corruption had been thoroughly institutionalized. A powerful political-military-industrial complex had come into being. As Henry S. Olcott, special investigator for the U.S. War and Navy departments, lamented in The War’s Carnival of Fraud (1878),
It is my deliberate conviction, based upon the inspection of many bureaus, and the examination of some thousands of witnesses, in every walk of life, that at least twenty, if not twenty-five percent of the entire expenditures during the Rebellion, was tainted with fraud.
At the same time, this new system was impoverishing Northern laborers, whose wages, when adjusted for inflation, had fallen by one third. When, in response to such deteriorating economic conditions, Northern workers tried to unionize and strike in Cold Springs, New York; West Point, New York; Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; and Tioga County, Pennsylvania, Lincoln directed the U.S. Army to suppress them, as he had directed the U.S. Army to suppress the Confederacy and the Plains Indians.
On November 4, 1866, Lord Acton wrote to Robert E. Lee,
I saw in State Rights the only availing check upon the absolutism of the sovereign will, and secession filled me with hope, not as the destruction but as the redemption of Democracy. . . . Therefore I deemed that you were fighting the battles of our liberty, our progress, and our civilization; and I mourn for the stake which was lost at Richmond more deeply than I rejoice over that which was saved at Waterloo.
Leave a Reply